Verified:

aponic Game profile

Member
1879

Jan 22nd 2012, 22:02:42

AMERICAN MONETARY INSTITUTE
PO BOX 601, VALATIE, NY 12184
Tel. 518-392-5387, e-mail:
http://www.monetary.org
Stephen Zarlenga, Director

Dedicated to the independent study of monetary history, theory, and reform

The 1930s Chicago Plan and the American Monetary Act
by Stephen Zarlenga, AMI Monetary Reform Conference, Chicago, October, 2005

(Notes: CP refers to Chicago Plan by Ronnie J. Phillips; EP refers to Economic Policy for a Free Society by Henry Simons)

>>>> Why is monetary reform so critically important?

Because the money power has more impact on citizens day to day lives than the Executive, Legislative and Judicial branches. It’s really a fourth branch of government, and leaving it in private hands is dangerous and unacceptable – it negates the balancing of powers principle of our constitution and creates an aristocracy – a plutocracy – the rule by wealth.

A privately controlled money system can nullify hard-won reforms in other areas such as the environment, medical care, or peace initiatives because such concentration of wealth and power will eventually overwhelm and be used against the people to unwind whatever other gains we’ve achieved. Witness the attack on Roosevelt’s social security reform. You can’t secure real progress with the private control of society’s money system behind your lines.

>>>> What does monetary reform really mean?

It means establishing a fair system that doesn’t give special privileges to some and disadvantage to others – that doesn’t concentrate wealth and power. It means helping the society create values for living well.

You are welcome to receive a draft of the latest version of the American Monetary Act. Comments are invited. If you think someone should see it, please ask me to forward a copy. We’re seeking commitment to this now – we’re writing what it would take to legally implement the three-part reform in Chapter 24 of The Lost Science of Money by Stephen Zarlenga (abbreviated as LSM hereon).

It’s vitally important to be ready with a workable plan – when not if – the next financial meltdown occurs. No one knows when that will be, since there’s tremendous power in the control over a money system, but warning signs have been there for years. It could be triggered by a couple of bad hurricanes!

The American Monetary Act is part of a long reform tradition going back to the Chicago Plan of the Great Depression (and that plan was close to one advanced independently by the great scientist Frederick Soddy in Britain in 1926).

>>>> Let’s start in December 1932:

It’s been only 20 years since the Federal Reserve was created by America’s banking ‘elite’ (see LSM, Ch. 19). But in those brief 20 years, the Fed brought America to its knees:

* Farms were wrecked with huge debt and falling land prices.
* Factories were closed.
* Exchanges were destroyed.
* Banks were closing.
* The economy collapsed – people couldn’t find work and many were hungry.

From 1929 to 1932:
* National income dropped 52%.
* Industrial production fell 47%.
* Wholesale prices fell 32%.
* The real value of debt rose 140%.
* Unemployment rose 329% from 3.5 to 15 million people, over a quarter of our workforce was unemployed.

All that destruction in less than 20 years!!

In that horrendous climate, many economists were aware that the banking system caused the problem and major changes were needed. One fear of bankers and economists was that all the banks would simply be nationalized, because People were angry. They feared violent revolution might be sparked.

>>>> In this atmosphere, the best economic minds in the country devised a reform plan:

Henry Simons from the University of Chicago created the proposal and prominent economists from other universities joined him in what became known as the “Chicago Plan.”

Economists like Paul Douglas of the University of Chicago; Frank Graham and Charles Whittlesey of Princeton; Irving Fisher of Yale; Earl Hamilton of Duke; and Wilford King of NYU, to name a few.

One version was sent to all the academic economists – about a thousand in total. Of those responding, 235 from 157 universities agreed with the proposal; another 40 approved it with reservations; and only 45 disapproved. So the plan had broad professional support.

Variants of the Chicago Plan usually started by condemning the banking structure as foolish and harmful: “If the purpose of money and credit were to discourage the exchange of goods and services, to destroy periodically the wealth produced, to frustrate and trip those who save, our present monetary system (does that) most effectively!”

They dispensed with the gold standard as not a real standard, because the value of gold had changed violently up and down against commodities. From 1914 to 1917 wholesale prices rose 65% and then increased another 55% to May 1920, so gold coins lost over 75% of their value against wholesale prices in the Fed’s first six years. Then, by June 1921, wholesale prices fell 56% against gold. “Hard money” advocates who believe that gold money has been stable should study these facts.

One version of the plan quoted Roosevelt’s referring to gold as an “old fetish of so-called international bankers.”

>>>> The main features of the Chicago Plan:

First: Only the U.S. Government would create money. The Federal Reserve banks would be nationalized, but not the individual member banks. The power to create money was to be removed from private banks by abolishing fractional reserves – the mechanism through which the banking system creates money. So the plan called for 100% reserves on checking accounts, which simply meant banks would be warehousing and transferring the money and charging fees for their services.

Second: The Plan separated the loan-making function, which can belong in private banks, from the moneycreation function, which belongs in government. Lending was still to be a private banking function, but lending deposited long-term savings money, not created credits. In this way, they’d restrict an unstable practice known as borrowing short and lending long – making long term loans with short term deposits. Some variations proposed this be done through mutual fund-like mechanisms, or by chartering entirely new types of banks.

Third: The proposal recognized the distinction between money and credit, which had been confused through fractional reserves and what was called the “real bills doctrine.” The confusion was seen as one of the causes of the depression, because when businesses reduced their borrowings on commercial bills, which occurs during any downturn, parts of the money supply had been automatically liquidated. The Chicago Plan saw the instability of this – that it aggravates a downturn.

>>>> Simons made this grand observation of the problem, which still afflicts us today:
“The mistake … lies in fearing money and trusting debt.”

And: “Money itself is highly amenable to democratic, legislative control, for no community wants a markedly appreciating or depreciating currency … but money is not easily manageable alongside a mass of private debt and private near-moneys … or alongside a mountain of public debt.” (EP, p. 199)

Some variations of the plan had the U.S. Government lending banks all or part of newly printed cash needed to achieve 100% reserves. This was a crucial part of the plan, because depositors were going to the banks and withdrawing their accounts, deflating the system.

This loaning of reserves feature also elegantly converted all the previously monetized bank credits into real U.S. money, on which the banks paid interest to our government. It post facto made them intermediaries, earning some reasonable spread for their loaning work.

>>>> The best economic minds supported the Chicago Plan:

Paul Douglas wrote: “This proposal will of course be opposed by the bankers from whom it takes the lucrative privilege of creating purchasing power. It would however insure the safety of deposits, give large revenues to the government, provide complete social control over monetary matters and prevent abnormal fluctuations in the capital market. At the same time it would permit the allocation of productive resources…to remain primarily in private hands. All in all it seems the most promising program for the reform of our monetary and
credit system…” (CP, p.141)

Frank Graham wrote it was self evident that the right of issuing money belongs in government, and that the banks seigniorage profits were a kind of tax on the community: “This privilege that the banks enjoy is in no way essential to the lending process.”

Marinner Eccles, who became Fed Chairman under Roosevelt, testified that the best course would be for the
government to nationalize the Federal Reserve banks.

Congressman Jerry Voorhis made the case for 100% reserves and putting money into circulation by paying
pensions and disabled persons. As late as 1945, Voorhis introduced legislation for a U.S. Monetary Authority
as our sole creator of money. (CP, p.162)

James Angell, who disagreed with parts of it, still wrote that “it would go far toward making economic activity reasonably stable” (CP, p. 144)

Maurice Allais, the great French economist, backed the plan and published a book on it in 1948.

Irving Fisher of Yale wrote on it extensively and popularly well into the 1940s.

The young Milton Friedman was the best known advocate for the Chicago Plan in the postwar period, writing: “Henry Simons held the view…which I share - that the creation of fiat currency should be a government monopoly.” Friedman testified on this before Congress as late as 1975 and in 1985 wrote: “I have not given up advocacy of one-hundred percent reserves.” Friedman thought the transition to 100% reserves would not be difficult – “say 25% a year from now, 50% two years from now, etc.” (CP, p. 173, 181)

But turning the Chicago Plan into law proved elusive. When University of Chicago’s Chancellor Maynard Hutchins sent a copy of the plan to Senator Bronson Cutting in December 1933, Cutting asked him to draft a bill. Four months later he telegrammed Hutchins asking where it was, and Simons went to present the essentials of the plan to Cutting, who introduced it in the Senate on June 6th, 1934 (S. 3744). Wright Patman introduced it
in the House (H.R. 9855).

The bill required 100% reserves on checking accounts, which it separated from savings accounts (which had to keep 5% reserves). It set up a Federal Monetary Authority to control the supply of currency and the buying and selling of government securities.

>>>> The American Monetary Act, a three-part reform to bring our money system under proper
public control, agrees in its main features with the Chicago Plan:

First: It incorporates the Federal Reserve banks into the U.S. Treasury, where money will be created by the government as money, not as private interest-bearing debt; and will be spent into circulation to promote the general welfare, and be monitored to be neither inflationary nor deflationary.

Second: It removes the banks privilege to create purchasing media through the fractional reserve system. Fractional reserves are elegantly ended by the U.S. Government initially loaning banks enough money at interest to bring reserves to 100% , converting all the past monetized credit into U.S. government money. (Note: This feature is altered significantly in the latest version, where the banks automatically owe the U.S. Treasury the amount of their credit that has been turned into money.) Banks then act as intermediaries: accepting deposits and loaning them out to borrowers – what people think they do now.

Third: It Spends newly-created money into circulation on infrastructure, including education and health care needed for a growing society, starting with the $2.2 trillion that the American Society of Civil Engineers estimate is needed for infrastructure repair, over the next 5 years; creating good jobs across our nation, reinvigorating local economies and re-funding all levels of government.

The false specter of inflation is always raised against such suggestions that our government fulfill its responsibility to furnish the nation’s money supply. But that knee-jerk reaction is the result of decades, even centuries, of propaganda against government. When one actually examines the monetary record, as The Lost Science of Money does, it becomes clear that government has a far superior record issuing and controlling money than bankers have.

So both plans envision taking over the Federal Reserve System and regional Federal Reserve banks. Both separate the money-creation and money-lending functions; placing the money-creation function in government and leaving the money-lending function in banks. Both set up national monetary authorities to control the money supply.

One difference between the plans is their greater awe of the “free market.” But the empirical nourishment we’ve received since they wrote calls for greater care in defining what’s meant by “free market” terminology. They strongly supported free markets, but their definition differed from the present conception.

For example, Henry Simons thought only stiff governmental regulation could create free market conditions. He wrote: “The presentation of laissez faire as a do nothing policy is misleading…it’s an obvious responsibility of the state…to maintain the legal and institutional framework within which competition can function effectively…the state (must have)…heavy responsibilities and large control functions” (EP, p.42-43)

Like the great 19th century reformer Henry George, Simons strongly believed that companies like railroads and
utilities should all be government owned: “The state should face the necessity of actually taking over, owning and managing directly both the railroads and the utilities, and all other industries in which it is impossible to maintain effectively competitive conditions.”(EP, p. 50-51)

Greater attention to defining “free markets” might have avoided their current degeneration into mere forms of kleptocracy, falsely promoted under the banner of freedom. Better yet, instead of misusing the term free, the word fair is what people really have mind. Some groups equated free markets with no governmental regulation – just the opposite of what’s needed to have real “free markets.” Another difference was their preference for an automatic system with little discretion. We are not so worried about that.

The American Monetary Act goes beyond the Chicago plan in some important improvements derived from the lessons of history – experience with the Bank of England’s nationalization in 1946, and our American experience of the past 50 years:

First: The Act proposes that infrastructure expenditures, including education and health care and farming parity programs, be used as mechanisms to get newly created money spent into circulation to promote the general welfare. We’ve observed that the privately controlled money system can’t or won’t make the necessary infrastructure expenditures.

Second: The Act introduces considerations of fairness, sustainability, sound environmental practice and social cohesion as values in monetary decision making. In other words moral considerations are explicitly considered. I wish we were the first to do this, but Article Two of the treaty protocols establishing the European System of Central Banks and the Euro beat us to it, and it’s already operational in the Euro system. That Euro provision is quoted in Chapter 23 of the The Lost Science of Money book: “To promote throughout the Community a harmonious and balanced development of economic activities, sustainable and non-inflationary growth respecting the environment, a high level of employment and of social protection, the raising of the standard of living and quality of life, and economic and social cohesion and solidarity among Member States.” (However, it says this is to be done “without prejudice to the objective of price stability,” by which they mean less than 2% inflation.)

Third: The Act places more reasonable nationwide legal limits on the charging of interest, with an 8% cap – about what it was under most state laws until 1980/81. It’s obscene that people are being forced to pay over 30% p.a. interest.

Friends have told us that economists and bankers will strongly object to that, and to other parts of this proposal. But we didn’t expect them as allies in this fight – a fight we didn’t start, but are involuntary participants in. Remember billionaire speculator Warren Buffet’s warning remark: “If there is class war in the United States, my class is winning.”

He was being facetious – Buffet would never describe the purposeful destruction of our most vulnerable fellow citizens and their children, by the ‘most clever’, as “winning!” He’d probably join me in calling it cannibalism and agree that indigestion and worse is coming.

But finally, let’s remember that Warren Buffet’s role as a speculator is largely negative and certainly less creative economically than the average bricklayer.

>>>> Why didn’t the Chicago Plan pass?

First: There was no understanding or support for the proposal among the electorate. Only Irving Fisher seems to have understood the necessity for popularizing the matter. Simons himself got cold feet and shied away from promoting the plan, desiring to remain on a level of professorial discussion. He even threw a wet towel on Fisher, who was promoting the reform, suggesting that Fisher avoid popularizing the idea! Simons was demanding perfection from his own proposal and was being overly cautious. The proper goal was not perfection, but should have simply been the substantial improvement that the Chicago Plan clearly represented over the existing system. Instead, Simons became obsessed with how banks would evade the reforms.

Second: The Plan was mishandled politically. Senator Cutting appears to have misunderstood his own bill, and incorrectly said in interviews that credit as well as money creation was also to be a sole function of government.

Third: The bill suffered a major setback when Cutting died in an airplane crash in May, 1935, while being forced to defend his election results in New Mexico by challenges from the Roosevelt Administration, which was then held responsible for his death.

The last attempt at 100% reserves was when Senator Nye of North Dakota tried to place it in part of the Administration’s 1935 banking reform legislation, but his amendment was defeated.

The FDR administration had its own banking reform bill and remained ambiguous on the Chicago Plan, never commenting on it even though the political climate and professional support for the plan was sufficient to get it passed, had they made some effort.

Instead, his Treasury Secretary Morganthau was trying to make minor adjustments without fundamentally challenging the banking system.

The brilliant economist Lauchlin Currie had taken up the fight for hundred percent reserves from within the administration. Currie pointed out that economists had not really agreed on the nature of money and focused his attention to defining what is money in our system. But he made 2 political errors:

First, he thought he could “sneak” 100% reserves through in the administration’s 1935 banking legislation with a provision giving the Fed the power to raise reserves. He thought “we’ll just get them raised to 100%.” But Senator Carter Glass, representing banker interests, easily blocked this by putting in a provision in the conference committee limiting the reserve requirement to double what they were at that time, which was about 15%.

Second, Currie made the error of compromising in advance, writing: “An advisor in Washington is of limited usefulness unless he acquires some sense of what is feasible and how projects and policies should be presented to have the best chance of being adopted.” (CP, p.128)

I completely disagree regarding this type of reform. Promoting the reform in terms of morality rather than mechanics and economics is the better approach. The only time that such major reforms become possible are when either enough people are educated on the matter, or during a crisis, when no-one cares what the economists and bankers want, and then compromise is both unnecessary and counterproductive.

Remember, we are promoting a reform that would be good for over 99

Edited By: aponic on Jan 22nd 2012, 22:06:23
See Original Post
SOF
Cerevisi

de1i Game profile

Member
1639

Jan 22nd 2012, 22:15:14

TLDR

Klown Game profile

Member
967

Jan 22nd 2012, 23:51:35

Originally posted by de1i:
TLDR

aponic Game profile

Member
1879

Jan 23rd 2012, 0:00:16

>>>> Why is monetary reform so critically important?

Because the money power has more impact on citizens day to day lives than the Executive, Legislative and Judicial branches. It’s really a fourth branch of government, and leaving it in private hands is dangerous and unacceptable – it negates the balancing of powers principle of our constitution and creates an aristocracy – a plutocracy – the rule by wealth.

A privately controlled money system can nullify hard-won reforms in other areas such as the environment, medical care, or peace initiatives because such concentration of wealth and power will eventually overwhelm and be used against the people to unwind whatever other gains we’ve achieved. Witness the attack on Roosevelt’s social security reform. You can’t secure real progress with the private control of society’s money system behind your lines.
SOF
Cerevisi

smlandau84 Game profile

Member
1949

Jan 23rd 2012, 1:19:14

meh.

Garry Owen Game profile

Member
849

Jan 23rd 2012, 1:27:39

People that believe this kind of stuff are really, really scary.



aponic Game profile

Member
1879

Jan 23rd 2012, 1:33:31

"this stuff"? Could you be more specific? Are you talking about the creation of money (capital) through the writing of debt, the notion that banks can create money into existence charging P + I (Principle and Interest) and continuously concentrate wealth from the community at large to the bank, or are you talking about reforming the process?

SOF
Cerevisi

Grimm Game profile

Member
175

Jan 23rd 2012, 2:19:10

Austrian Economists - there's a reason why no one takes them seriously.*

*Hint: they're the only school of economists who don't use math in their professional publications.

Unsympathetic Game profile

Member
364

Jan 23rd 2012, 4:27:26

No current economic model includes private debt rather than just public [governmental] debt.

Prof. Keen's blog at debtdeflation is the only one that does. It's much more relevant than strict Austrian.

aponic Game profile

Member
1879

Jan 23rd 2012, 4:30:39

You have a link?
SOF
Cerevisi

qzjul Game profile

Administrator
Game Development
10,263

Jan 23rd 2012, 5:36:02

i will read this tomorrow at work
Finally did the signature thing.

Dibs Ludicrous Game profile

Member
6702

Jan 23rd 2012, 8:12:41

does all that mean that they'll be giving me back the money i paid for alcohol and tobacco taxes, auto insurance, and credit card interest?
There are no messages in your Inbox.
Elvis has left the building.

LaFinglolrik Game profile

Member
206

Jan 23rd 2012, 8:37:01

Dont drink, dont smoke, dont drive, dont use creditcard.

Its all illuminati!
http://www.youtube.com/watch?v=RX6_W-SyiO4

TNTroXxor Game profile

Member
1295

Jan 23rd 2012, 8:52:55

Abolish currency. The only way to go forward.

Work to better ourselves - Jean Luc Picard
Originally posted by JJ23:
i havent been deleted since last set

Dibs Ludicrous Game profile

Member
6702

Jan 23rd 2012, 10:27:24

Originally posted by LaFinglolrik:
Dont drink, dont smoke, dont drive, dont use creditcard.

think i can find a more interesting way to die instead of it being caused by pure boredom.
There are no messages in your Inbox.
Elvis has left the building.

Oceana Game profile

Member
1111

Jan 23rd 2012, 20:02:26

Federal Reserve ?The source of Inflation?

http://www.nma.org/.../gold/his_gold_prices.pdf

CrazyMatt Game profile

Member
265

Jan 23rd 2012, 20:03:27

boringgg

Getafix Game profile

Member
EE Patron
3423

Jan 23rd 2012, 23:09:12

"The New York Times, in December, 1933, working with Felix Frankfurter (who wrote a rather poor book called Other Peoples Money, and later became a Supreme Court Justice)"

Hey, this guy was in the Rocky Horror Show too wasn't he? Thats who we need on the Supreme Court!

Reckless Game profile

Member
1190

Jan 23rd 2012, 23:56:59

I used to do monetary reform with my girl..now its doggy...girls are so picky

weasel Game profile

Member
101

Jan 26th 2012, 4:35:00

omg so long cant read, but i bet i agree 100%

EVO Internal Affairs Department

General Earl Game profile

Member
896

Jan 26th 2012, 6:27:13

tl;dr

next time please sum it up in point form or something :P
General Earl
----
Every time I read AT: http://i.imgur.com/jeryjn8.gif
︻╦╤─✮ ┄ ┄ RatttaTaatataatat!

qzjul Game profile

Administrator
Game Development
10,263

Jan 26th 2012, 15:40:31

TL;DR version is:

Banks shouldn't be allowed to hold fractional reserves, the Fed should be nationalized, so that the only entity allowed to modify the money supply is the government.
Finally did the signature thing.

martian Game profile

Game Moderator
Mod Boss
7828

Jan 26th 2012, 16:27:17

In order to keep my response (relatively) short I'm going to omit concrete examples and explanations which could be longer than your argument.

Without fractional reserve banking everything would be brought to a state of paralysis and we would be where we were pre-renaissance. We are no longer an agricultural based society.

Unfortunately the author's arguments limits itself in scope to the US and the circumstances leading up to and surrounding the great Depression of the 1930s. The limitation in scope cripples your argument. There is more to the world and monetary policies than the Chicago act and US monetary policy.

I'm not sure the arguments put forth denote a clear understanding of how the US monetary system in fact works. Laying the blame for the lack of public expenditure on social programs and infrastructure squarely on the monetary system itself is a great oversimplification. Many countries and large infrastructure projects both within and outside of the US have been successfully implemented both because of and regardless of the monetary system. The argument also doesn't take into account the historical and technological context now versus the 1930s nor does it take demographics into account. Nationalizing the banking system does little in the way of addressing many of these problems and an argument for/against is a separate issue.

There is the confusion of undue influence and concentration of power with the federal reserve.

you are all special in the eyes of fluff
(|(|
( ._.) -----)-->
(_(' )(' )

RUN IT IS A KILLER BUNNY!!!